October 10, 2016

Entrepreneurial Finance




Strategic Entrepreneurial Finance: From Value Creation to Realization

Darek Klonowski
Routledge, 27-Nov-2014 - Business & Economics - 420 pages

Entrepreneurial finance is a discipline that studies financial resource mobilization, resource allocation, risk moderation, optimization in financial contracting, value creation, and value monetization within the context of entrepreneurship. However, without proper strategic consideration the discipline is incomplete. This book examines how the activity of entrepreneurial finance can be enhanced via a concentration on value creation and through improved strategic decision-making.

The most unique feature of the book is its focus on value creation. For entrepreneurs, value creation is not a one-off activity, but rather a continuous cycle of incremental improvements across a wide range of business activities. Entrepreneurial value creation is described in four comprehensive stages: value creation, value measurement, value enhancement, and value realization, referred to as the C-MER model. This book focuses on what creates value rather than merely presenting value creation in a straight accounting framework.

At the same time, deliberate and tactical planning and implementation ensure that the firm does not ignore the components necessary for it to survive and flourish.Vigorous strategic deliberations maximize the entrepreneurial firm’s chances of making the right business decisions for the future, enable the firm to manage its available financial and non-financial resources in the most optimal manner, ensure that the necessary capital is secured to progress the development of the firm to its desired development level, and build value.

While financial considerations are important, the field of strategic entrepreneurial finance represents a fusion of three disciplines: strategic management, financial management, and entrepreneurship. This orientation represents a natural evolution of scholarship to combine specific domains and paradigms of naturally connected business disciplines and reflects the need to simultaneously examine business topics from different perspectives which may better encapsulate actual entrepreneurial practices.

https://books.google.co.in/books?id=IDOcBQAAQBAJ

Corporate Global Profits



Report McKinsey Global Institute September 2015
The new global competition for corporate profits
By Richard Dobbs, Tim Koller, Sree Ramaswamy, Jonathan Woetzel, James Manyika, Rohit Krishnan, and Nicolo Andreula

http://www.mckinsey.com/business-functions/strategy-and-corporate-finance/our-insights/the-new-global-competition-for-corporate-profits

The Theory of the Growth of the Firm


Theory Developed Edith Penrose

Firms are collections of productive resources that are organized in an administrative framework which partly determines the amount and type of services that the resources yield. As they go
along with their productive operations, firms - or, more precisely, the management team - obtain increased knowledge of the services that may be obtained from resource. The results of such learning processes is, first, the expansion of the firm’s “productive opportunity set” (the opportunities that the
firm’s management team can see and can take advantage of) and, second, the release of managerial excess resources that can be put to use in other, mostly related, business areas. Since the opportunity costs of excess resources are zero, there will be a strong internal incentive for such diversification which in turn causes the firm to grow - an idea that according to Penrose destroys the notion of
the firm’s optimum size

However, the managerial resources inherited from the past set a limit to the firm’s rate of growth - what has become known in the literature as “the Penrose effect” (Slater 1980). (In mergers and acquisitions we see the point. Firms with manageral slack, that is excess managerial resources do acquisitions).

 In Penrose (1959), this is rationalized by pointing to the difficulties of socializing new managers that are needed for the expansion of the firm.

Later models (Baumol 1962; Marris 1964) imposed the Penrose effect exogenously (Gander 1991), but eventually it became subordinated under supposedly more general theories of adjustment costs in the theory of investment of the firm (Treadway 1970). Given this, and using a dynamic control theory
approach, the Penrose effect arises naturally as the profit-maximizing firm calculates its optimal time-profile of outputs.


The resource-based analysis of (sustained) competitive advantages may be seen as starting out from two basic empirical generalizations, namely that 1) there are systematic differences across firms in the extent to which they control resources that are necessary for implementing strategies, and 2) that these differences are relatively stable. The basic structure of the RBP emerges when these two generalizations are combined with fundamental assumptions that are to a large extent derived from economics. Among these assumptions are that 3) differences in firms’ resource endowments cause
performance differences, and 4) that firms seek to increase their economic performance. The fundamentals of the resource-based analysis of the conditions for sustained competitive advantage are basically simple (Peteraf 1993).

Some argue that Penrose's theorizing leads us to what would in modern management studies be called “strategic human resource management” where the focus is on the development of the firm’s pool of talents with particular goals in mind.

Imposing the requirement of choosing the optimal trade-off between the gains from diversification and the costs of managing a diversified firm then allows one to derive the optimal/equilibrium degree of diversification of the firm.


If services are produced endogenously (and continuously) through various intra-firm learning processes involving increased knowledge of resources, “new combinations of resources” (1959: 85), and an expanding productive opportunity set, there is no equilibrium size. Moreover, because of the difficulties of managing new resources and services, and of assimilating new managers in the firm, firm growth is not smooth or “balanced” (as in Marris 1964; Slater 1980). On the contrary, growth rates in succeeding periods will typically be negatively serially correlated, so that high growth in one period is followed by low growth and vice versa. In fact, this is the true “Penrose effect”, and a first indication that even on this fundamental level, Penrose has been partly misrepresented in the literature.

“In the long run”, Penrose explains, ... the profitability, survival and growth of a firm does not depend so much on the efficiency with which it is able to organize the production of even a widely diversified range of products as it does on the ability of the firm to establish one or more wide and relatively impregnable ‘bases’ from which it can adapt and extend its operations in an
uncertain, changing and competitive world (1959: 137).

A firm is basically a collection of resources. Consequently, if we can assume that businessmen believe there is more to know about the
resources they are working with than they do know at any given time,
and that more knowledge would be likely to improve the efficiency
and profitability of their firm, then unknown and unused productive
services immediately become of considerable importance, not only
because the belief that they exist acts as an incentive to acquire new
knowledge, but also because they shape the scope and direction of the
search for knowledge (Penrose 1959: 77).

Thus, firm
development is essentially an evolutionary and cumulative process of “resource
learning” (Mahoney 1995), in which increased knowledge of the firm’s resources
both help create options for further expansion and increases absorptive capacity
(Cohen and Levinthal 1990), or, to use Penrose’s terminology an expanding
“productive opportunity”.


The firm’s productive opportunity, arguably the key concept of The Theory of
the Growth of the Firm (cf. also Fransman 1994: 744), is “... the productive
possibilities that its ‘entrepreneurs’’ see and can take advantage of. A theory of
the growth of the firm is essentially an examination of the changing productive
opportunity of firms” (1959: 31-32). Thus, the notion of productive opportunity
is quite a central notion in The Theory of the Growth of the Firm.

 Penrose notes that “... the decision to search for opportunities
is an enterprising decision requiring entrepreneurial intuition and imagination
and must precede the ‘economic’ decision to go ahead with the examination of
opportunities for expansion” (1959: 34).


Source: Paper by Foss






October 8, 2016

Competitor - Competitive Intelligence Analysis Techniques


You need to get objective or subjective information about your competitors and potential competitor that provides output created by the following analyses.  Your strategy is based on your view of competitor's likely actions in the future based on their current products, markets, R&D activities, capabilities, competences, resources and relationships.


SWOT
SCP Framework ( Structure-Conduct-Performance)
ADL Matrix
Porter's Five Forces Analysis
Industry cost curves
Value Net
The Space Matrix
PEST
Inflection point analysis
Hypercompetition


50 Competitive Intelligence Analysis Techniques
7 OCTOBER 2013 | BY ESTELLE METAYER
http://competia.com/50-competitive-intelligence-analysis-techniques

Strategy for Growth in Mature Industries



Growing When Your Industry Doesn’t
Success and profits flow to companies with uniquely valuable market propositions — regardless of their sector.

by Kasturi Rangan and Evan Hirsh
strategy+business: Corporate Strategies and News Articles on Global Business, Management, Competition and Marketing
Published: April 28, 2014 / Summer 2014 / Issue 75
http://www.strategy-business.com/article/00251?gko=cb1ac

How to thrive in a slow-growth industry
LRed - Sunday 24th May 2015
http://www.leadershipreview.net/how-thrive-slow-growth-industry

http://www.pm.lth.se/fileadmin/pm/Exjobb/Exjobb_2014/Sara_Tavakolizadeh/Growth_strategies_in_mature_markets.pdf

October 7, 2016

Strategic Leadership



According to Hoskisson et al (2004) Strategic Leadership is:
“…the managerial ability to anticipate, envision, maintain flexibility, and empower others to create
strategic change as necessary”.

Rowe (2001) emphasises the need at the top of organisations of what he labels “Strategic Leadership”. He describes Strategic Leadership as the …ability to influence others to voluntarily make day to day decisions that enhance the long-term viability of the organisation while maintaining its short term financial stability.


Hoskisson, R., Hitt, M. and Ireland R. D. 2004. Strategic Leadership. In Competing for Advantage. South Western: Thompson.

Rowe, W. G. 2001. Creating Wealth in Organisations: The Role of Strategic Leadership. Academy of
Management Review, 2001, Volume 15, No. 1.


THE IMPORTANCE OF DIFFERENT LEADERSHIP ROLES IN THE STRATEGIC MANAGEMENT PROCESS
MOJAKI S MOSIA
THEO H VELDSMAN
Leadership in Performance and Change
Department of Human Resource Management
Rand Afrikaans University
SA Journal of Human Resource Management, 2004, 2 (1), 26-36
http://www.sajhrm.co.za/index.php/sajhrm/article/viewFile/36/36

STRATEGY AND THE IMPORTANCE OF STRATEGIC LEADERSHIP
By James Redmond, BBS, MBS, ACMA: Examiner - Professional 2 Strategy &
Leadership
http://www.cpaireland.ie/docs/default-source/Students/exam-related-articles-2015/cpa-article---strategy-and-leadership-final.pdf?sfvrsn=2

10 Principles of Strategic Leadership
How to develop and retain leaders who can guide your organization through times of fundamental change. See also "Find Your Strategic Leaders.”

by Jessica Leitch, David Lancefield, and Mark Dawson, PWC
http://www.strategy-business.com/article/10-Principles-of-Strategic-Leadership?gko=25cec

WHAT SENIOR LEADERS DO: THE NINE ROLES OF STRATEGIC LEADERSHIP
BY
LOREN APPELBAUM
EXECUTIVE CONSULTANT,
SUCCESSION
MANAGEMENT PRACTICE,
DDI
MATTHEW PAESE, PH.D.
PRACTICE LEADER,
EXECUTIVE SUCCESSION
MANAGEMENT,
DDI
http://www.ddiworld.com/DDI/media/white-papers/WhatSeniorLeadersDoTheNineRoles_wp_ddi.pdf

Distribution Warehouse

A distribution warehouse is a building and a place where items for distribution are stored. It serves as storage for products form the manufacturer to the distributor before these products are distributed to various retail customers.

Who uses a distribution warehouse?

The Manufacturing Company. They use the warehouse in order to store the goods and the items that they have manufactured and are to be delivered to the distributors.
Third party distributors. These are the entities that the manufacturing company delivers their products to. These entities are the ones responsible for supplying a place with certain goods and products from the manufacturing company.
Retail stores. This refers to the stores that sell products in retail. The items they usually place inside the distribution warehouse are those items that they sell. They use the warehouse to store the stocks or inventory they have.

The Benefits of Having a Distribution Warehouse

Distribution centers or companies need to have a distribution warehouse if they want to avail of these benefits:

Time-savings. A distribution warehouse can really save distributors a lot of time when it comes to distributing all the items. The distribution warehouse with its warehouse storage system can give convenience since it makes the items and the products to be distributed more organized. It can save workers a lot of time and effort trying to distribute the products or in managing their products.

Money-savings. A distribution warehouse is the best solution to protect the goods or the products that distributors are trying to distribute to retail outlets. When you have a distribution warehouse, you are ensuring that all the goods are kept in good condition and retain their quality. This is because a distribution warehouse is built to achieve these things. They are usually built with the right temperature that can help distributors achieve their purpose in terms of preserving the quality and the condition of the products. This way, they can save a lot of money as they are going to prevent spoiled goods and damaged items.

http://www.kardex-remstar.com/en/lift-storage-systems/distribution-warehouse.html

Jobs in Distribution Warehouse

Store distribution manager
The store distribution manager analyses the supply chain, ensuring distribution centres can accommodate the volume of goods required by stores.

Customer distribution manager
The customer distribution manager is responsible for operating and developing the order distribution business, from warehouse to customer.

Transport operational coordinator
The transport operational coordinator is the lynchpin between the firm and its carriers, ensuring an efficient flow of goods.

Warehouse operations manager
The warehouse operations manager ensures efficiency within the distribution centre and responds to the needs of the supply chain.

Quality manager
The quality manager is responsible for quality control in the warehouse and efficiency of delivery to the customer.

Transport business developer
The transport business developer builds and maintains relationships between the firm  and its carriers whilst negotiating mutually beneficial transport scenarios.

Goods flow coordinator
The goods flow coordinator secures the highest product availability to the customer with the lowest possible supply chain costs.

http://www.ikea.com/ms/en_US/jobs/business_types/distribution_logistics/


Warehouse & Distribution Science - Free Text book


Warehouse & Distribution Science by J. Bartholdi and S. Hackman
http://www.warehouse-science.com/


You are also welcome to use any of these:

Supplementary materials
Warehouse software
Warehouse tours
Class projects
Order-picking by bucket brigade
http://www.warehouse-science.com/


https://www.stitchlabs.com/resource/guides/optimizing-warehouse-management/


Updated 10 October 2016